In economics, the
marginal propensity to consume (MPC) is an empirical metric that quantifies induced consumption, the concept that the increase in personal consumer spending (consumption) occurs with an increase in disposable income
(income after taxes and transfers). The proportion of the disposable
income which individuals desire to spend on consumption is known as
propensity to consume. MPC is the proportion of additional income that
an individual desires to consume. For example, if a household earns one
extra dollar of disposable income, and the marginal propensity to
consume is 0.65, then of that dollar, the household will spend 65 cents
and save 35 cents.
Mathematically, the

function is expressed as the derivative of the consumption function

with respect to disposable income

.

or
, where
is the change in consumption, and
is the change in disposable income that produced the consumption.
Marginal propensity to consume can be found by dividing change in consumption by a change in income, or

. The MPC can be explained with the simple example:
INCOME |
CONSUMPTION |
120 |
120 |
180 |
170 |
Here

;

Therefore,

or 83%. For example, suppose you receive a bonus with your paycheck,
and it's $500 on top of your normal annual earnings. You suddenly have
$500 more in income than you did before. If you decide to spend $400 of
this marginal increase in income on a new business suit, your marginal
propensity to consume will be 0.8 (

).
The above figure illustrates the consumption function. The slope of the
consumption function tells us how much consumption increases when
disposable income increases by one rupee. That is, the slope of the
consumption function is the MPC.
The marginal propensity to consume is measured as the ratio of the
change in consumption to the change in income, thus giving us a figure
between 0 and 1. The MPC can be more than one if the subject borrowed
money to finance expenditures higher than their income. One minus the
MPC equals the marginal propensity to save (in a two sector closed economy), both of which are crucial to Keynesian economics and are key variables in determining the value of the multiplier.
The MPC is the rate of change in the Average propensity to consume
(APC). When income increases, the MPC falls but more than the APC.
Contrariwise, when income falls, the MPC rises and the APC also rises
but at a slower rate than the former. Such changes are only possible
during cyclical fluctuations whereas in the short-run there is no change
in the MPC and

.
The MPC relies heavily upon the real (inflation-adjusted) rate of
interest. A high rate of interest causes spending in the future to
become increasingly attractive due to the intertemporal substitution
effect on consumption. Because a rate increase primarily decreases the
present value of lifetime wealth, the consumer relies on becoming a
lender to offset this effect. In a two period model, as

increases with the interest rate, so does future income [

]. Therefore, every dollar of current income spent by the consumer is

dollars the consumer will not be able to spend in the second period.
Economists often distinguish between the marginal propensity to
consume out of permanent income, and the marginal propensity to consume
out of temporary income, because if consumers expect a change in income
to be permanent, then they have a greater incentive to increase their
consumption (Barro and Grilli, p. 417-8). This implies that the
Keynesian multiplier should be
larger
in response to permanent changes in income than it is in response to
temporary changes in income (though the earliest Keynesian analyses
ignored these subtleties). However, the distinction between permanent
and temporary changes in income is often subtle in practice, and it is
often quite difficult to designate a particular change in income as
being permanent or temporary. What is more, the marginal propensity to
consume should also be affected by factors such as the prevailing
interest rate and the general level of consumer surplus that can be derived from purchasing.
MPC
Contents
- 1 MPC and the Multiplier
- 2 Significance of MPC
- 2.1 MPC and nature of country
|
MPC and the Multiplier
MPC’s importance depends on the multiplier theory. The value of the
multiplier—is determined by MPC. The higher the MPC, the higher the
multiplier and vice-versa. The relationship between the multiplier and
the propensity to consume is as follows:


(where
is
)



(where ,
is multiplier and 
Since

is the MPC, the multiplier

is, by definition, equal to

. The multiplier can also be derived from MPS (marginal propensity to save) and it is the reciprocal of MPS,
(MPC) |
(MPS) [ ] |
(multiplier coefficient) |
0 |
1 |
1 |
1/2 |
1/2 |
2 |
2/3 |
1/3 |
3 |
3/4 |
1/4 |
4 |
4/5 |
1/5 |
5 |
8/9 |
1/9 |
9 |
9/10 |
1/10 |
10 |
1 |
0 |
α |
The above table shows that the size of the multiplier varies directly
with the MPC and inversely with the MPS. Since the MPC is always
greater than zero and less than one (i.e.

), the multiplier is always between one and infinity (

).
If the multiplier is one, it means that the whole increment of income
is saved and nothing is spent because the MPC is zero. On the other
hand, an infinite multiplier implies that MPC is equal one and the
entire increment of income is spent on consumption. It will soon lead to
full employment in the economy and then create a limitless inflationary
spiral. But these are rare phenomenon. Therefore, the multiplier
coefficient varies between one and infinity.
Significance of MPC
The MPC is the rate of change in the APC. When income increases, the
MPC falls but more than the APC. Contrariwise, when income falls, the
MPC rises and the APC also rises but at a slower rate than the former.
Such changes are only possible during cyclical fluctuations whereas in
the short-run there is no change in the MPC and

.
Keynes is concerned primarily with the MPC, for his analysis pertains
to the short-run while the APC is useful in the long-run analysis. The
post-Keynesian economists have come to the conclusion that over the
long-run APC and MPC are equal and approximate 0.9. In the Keynesian
analysis the MPC is given more prominence. Its value is assumed to be
positive and less than unity which means that when income increases the
whole of it is not spent on consumption. On the contrary, when income
falls, consumption expenditure does not decline in the same proportion
and never becomes zero. The Keynesian hypothesis is that the marginal
propensity to consume is positive but less than unity (

)
is of great analytical and practical significance. Besides telling us
that consumption is an increasing function of income and it increases by
less than the increment of income, this hypothesis helps in explaining
1) The theoretical possibility of general overproduction or
‘underemployment equilibrium’ and also 2) The relative stability of a
highly developed industrial economy. For it imply that the gap between
income and consumption at all high levels of income is too wide to be
easily filled by investment with the possible consequences that the
economy may fluctuate around underemployment equilibrium. Thus the
economic significance of the MPC lies in filling the gap between income
and consumption through planned investment to maintain the desired level
of income.
MPC and nature of country
The MPC is higher in the case of poor than in case of rich people.
The greater a person’s income, the more of her or his basic human needs
will have already been met, and the greater his or her tendency to save
in order to provide for future will be. The marginal propensity to save
of the richer classes is greater than that of the poorer classes. If, at
any time, it is desired to increase aggregate consumption, then the
purchasing power should be transferred from the richer classes (with low
propensity to consume) to the poorer classes (with a higher propensity
to consume). Likewise, if it is desired to reduce community consumption,
the purchasing power must be taken away from the poorer classes by
taxing consumption.
The marginal propensity to consume is higher in a
poor country and lower in the case of rich country. The reason is same
as stated above. In the case of rich country, most of the basic needs of
the people have already been satisfied, and all the additional
increments of income are saved, resulting in a higher marginal
propensity to save but in a lower marginal propensity to consume. In a
poor country, on the other hand, most of the basic needs of the people
remain unsatisfied so that additional increments of income go to
increase consumption, resulting in a higher marginal propensity to
consume and a lower marginal propensity to save. This is the reason MPC
is higher in the underdeveloped countries of Asia and Africa, and lower
in developed countries such as the United States, the United Kingdom,
and Germany.